Capital and Its Structure (LvMI) and over one million other books are available for Amazon Kindle. Learn more
Have one to sell? Sell on Amazon
Flip to back Flip to front
Listen Playing... Paused   You're listening to a sample of the Audible audio edition.
Learn more
See this image

Capital and Its Structure (Studies in economic theory) Hardcover – April 1, 1981


See all 8 formats and editions Hide other formats and editions
Amazon Price New from Used from
Kindle
"Please retry"
Hardcover
"Please retry"
$2,432.64 $39.95
Unknown Binding
"Please retry"
--This text refers to the Kindle Edition edition.
NO_CONTENT_IN_FEATURE

Kindle Business Book Daily Deal
Today only, James McQuivey's "Digital Disruption" is on sale for only $1.99. Shop now

Product Details

  • Series: Studies in economic theory
  • Hardcover: 130 pages
  • Publisher: New York University Press (April 1, 1981)
  • Language: English
  • ISBN-10: 0836207408
  • ISBN-13: 978-0836207408
  • Product Dimensions: 8.9 x 6 x 0.5 inches
  • Shipping Weight: 8.8 ounces
  • Average Customer Review: 5.0 out of 5 stars  See all reviews (4 customer reviews)
  • Amazon Best Sellers Rank: #4,414,162 in Books (See Top 100 in Books)

Editorial Reviews

Review

“Anderson's book is a solid introduction to the anthropology of food for students and general readers. It is clear, well-written, spiced with interesting examples, and illustrated with many evocative photographs taken by the author and by Barbara Anderson.”
- Journal of the Royal Anthropological Institute



“Anderson's view of the relationship between the biological and the cultural is nicely provocative, and his rich personal fieldwork experiences greatly enliven the pages of Everyone Eats.”
- Sidney W. Mintz, author of Tasting Food, Tasting Freedom: Excursions into Eating, Culture, and the Past



“Plenty of cultural insights and background history lend to a survey particularly recommended for college-level students of anthropology and social science.”
- The Bookwatch, The Midwest Book Review



Everyone Eats is anthropology at its best, an exceptional blend of biological and cultural explanation that reveals our relationship with food and eating. Anderson's personal ethnographic experience as a nutritional anthropologist among cultures from around the world will leave the reader with a sense of wonderment about the fundamental human act of eating. Throughout the book Anderson develops a deep social conscience about the problems of over—and under-nutrition—that face the world today.” - Barrett P. Brenton, Associate Editor of The Encyclopedia of Food and Culture



“Although intended for the general public and not as a textbook, this book is recommended for higher education, especially advanced courses.” - CHOICE,Highly Recommended

--This text refers to an alternate Hardcover edition.

About the Author

E. N. Anderson is Professor of Anthropology at the University of California, Riverside. His previous books include The Food of China and Ecologies of the Heart: Emotion, Belief, and the Environment.

--This text refers to an alternate Hardcover edition.

More About the Author

Discover books, learn about writers, read author blogs, and more.

Customer Reviews

5.0 out of 5 stars
5 star
4
4 star
0
3 star
0
2 star
0
1 star
0
See all 4 customer reviews
Share your thoughts with other customers

Most Helpful Customer Reviews

9 of 9 people found the following review helpful By D. W. MacKenzie on April 5, 2008
Format: Hardcover
Lachmann is recognized (among Austrians at least) for stressing the importance of disequilibrium more so than most Austrians. Capital is always in disequilibrium, so we can only understand capital structure by thinking in terms of disequilibrium. While there is no doubt that Lachmann criticized neoclassical general equilibrium theory, there are other elements of his analysis that deserve attention.

Lachmann stressed the role of financial markets. Lachmann insisted that "When left free of political intervention, the market grows institutions in response to challenges ... Among these institutions forward markets and the stock exchange call for our particular attention" (p67). This is a critical point. Neoclassical economists never tire of pointing out that general equilibrium require a complete set of markets, including forward markets. Lachmann thought of capitalism as an evolutionary system, and certain financial markets evolve to solve coordination problems. Of course, financial markets are incomplete. But what is the alternative?

In my own interpretation, Lachmann's insight into how financial markets evolve to solve coordination problems is his most important contribution. His insight into financial markets explains his discontent with general equilibrium analysis, as well as the primary advantages of the capitalist system over its alternatives. Capital and its Structure is a short and insightful book. More economists should read it, including more Austrians.
Comment Was this review helpful to you? Yes No Sending feedback...
Thank you for your feedback. If this review is inappropriate, please let us know.
Sorry, we failed to record your vote. Please try again
6 of 6 people found the following review helpful By Hans Haneberg on July 12, 2006
Format: Hardcover
This is Ludwig Lachmann's best work on economics. Written in 1956, this small book made little to no impact upon the then dominant neo-classical paradigm, even though it should have. This can be explained because Lachmann was an advocate of Karl Menger's Austrian method and a pupil of Fredrick von Hayek at the London School of Economics. Both Hayek and the ideas of Menger were unfashionable during the publication of this work.

Lachmann dissects most neo-classical economic models for relying too heavily upon a homogeneous concept of capital. He reminds us in this small volume that capital goods are heterogeneous and valued as such through the eyes of the entrepreneur/individual actor.

In his own words:

"The generic concept of capital... has no measurable counterpart among material objects; it reflects the entrepreneurial appraisal of such objects. Beer barrels and blast-furnaces, harbour installations and hotel-room furniture are capital not by virtue of their physical properties but by virtue of their economic functions. Something is capital because the market, the consensus of entrepreneurial minds, regards it as capable of yielding an income (Lachmann 1956: xv)."

The impact of such a work is important, especially when thinking about business cycle theory. If integrated with other Austrian works, this idea solidifies the concept of Malinvestment, a distinctly Austrian term.
Comment Was this review helpful to you? Yes No Sending feedback...
Thank you for your feedback. If this review is inappropriate, please let us know.
Sorry, we failed to record your vote. Please try again
3 of 3 people found the following review helpful By James F. Mueller on June 10, 2008
Format: Hardcover
Peter Lewin is the only contemporary Austrian who has written at length on Lachmann's capital theory. This is almost ironic because, as Lewin himself notes, capital theory is probably the most important topic in Austrian economics and yet no Austrian since the 1970 revival has written about it.

Well for those who ever develop an interest in capital theory, the Austrian position can be found here in this short little book. Lachmann's book is a tour de force. It is important to remember that Lachmann is describing a world in perpetual disequilibrium (i.e., the real world). This means that the prices for goods are not yet equlibrium prices. Therefore, it makes no sense at all to speak of aggregate values of capital goods. We cannot add up all the capital goods (in monetary terms) and hope to get a reliable or meaningful measure of the value of capital. Now while it is clear that we cannot add computers and automobiles, Lachmann goes even further and argues that we cannot even add up their monetary values (prices) because these prices are disequilibrium prices. This is because all capital goods are used in some production plan. But not all production plans succeed. Business is about success AND failure. Therefore, the prices of these capital goods are not accurate because the use to which they are put will result in failure and error. Prices of capital goods in a disequilibrium world cannot serve as accurate indicators of value. This is why Lachmann spoke of capital as a "structure."

This is the theory of capital Lachmann employs in this book. He makes use of several illustrative examples throughout the book. This theory is also applied to financial markets and the Austrian business cycle theory, among other things.
Read more ›
Comment Was this review helpful to you? Yes No Sending feedback...
Thank you for your feedback. If this review is inappropriate, please let us know.
Sorry, we failed to record your vote. Please try again
1 of 1 people found the following review helpful By Steven H. Propp TOP 100 REVIEWER on November 27, 2012
Format: Paperback
Ludwig Lachmann (1906-1990) was a German economist who was a member of the Austrian School. This book was originally published in 1956. He wrote in the Preface to the second edition, "This book deals with the stock of social capital and its structure, not with income accruing to the various classes of its owners."(Pg. viii) He explained in the original Preface, "The chief object of this book is ... to outline a new approach and to show that it can be applied... and, above all, to emphasize the transmission of knowledge, the interaction of minds, as the ultimate agent of al economic processes." (Pg. xv-xvi)

He states, "this subjectivism of interpretation is something altogether different from the subjectivism of want which underlies our utility theory. The former yields provisional judgments to be confirmed by later experience, imperfect knowledge capable of being perfected. The latter can provide us with no new knowledge: we either have a want or do not have it." (Pg. 21)

He argues, "the results of past mistakes are there not merely to provide lessons, but to provide resources. In revising our expectations we not only have the knowledge, often dearly bought, of past mistakes ... to learn from, but also their physical counterpart, malinvested capital. Malinvested capital is still capital that can be adapted to other uses. This is the main problem of the theory of capital in a world of unexpected change." (Pg. 25)

He also asserts, "History shows that whenever left sufficiently free from political interference to evolve its responses to such challenges, the market economy has 'grown' the institutions necessary to deal with them. In particular, it has evolved institutions to protect the integrating forces of the price system from the disintegrating forces just described.
Read more ›
Comment Was this review helpful to you? Yes No Sending feedback...
Thank you for your feedback. If this review is inappropriate, please let us know.
Sorry, we failed to record your vote. Please try again

Customer Images

Search