Customer Review

54 of 65 people found the following review helpful
4.0 out of 5 stars More Truth and Less Unsupported Hype than Most Analyses, June 3, 2009
Verified Purchase(What's this?)
This review is from: The Crash of 2008 and What it Means: The New Paradigm for Financial Markets (Paperback)
George Soros presents a critique of and an alternative traditional economic theory, which denies the possibility of the sort of housing and credit bubbles that characterize the crash of 2008 in the United States. Soros is charming, disarming, self-effacing (except about his ability to conquer financial markets), never dismissive of other theories, and never aggrandizing his own approach by presenting straw-man versions of other approaches. I came away from this book with a good deal of respect for Soros as a thinker and as a human being.

Soros' central claim is that traditional economic theory holds that competitive markets tend toward equilibrium, and this is false. "The belief that markets tend toward equilibrium," he writes, "...is no better than Marxist dogma. Both ideologies cloak themselves in scientific guise in order to make themselves more acceptable, but the theories they invoke do not stand up to the test of reality." (p. 75) Soros calls this faulty approach "market fundamentalism."

I learned economic theory when I was a graduate student at Harvard. The central model I learned was called "general equilibrium (GE) theory," initiated by Walras in the late nineteenth century, and perfected in the mid-twentieth century by Debreu, Arrow, Hurwicz, Hahn, McKenzie and others. GE theory is the basic, underlying model in all of contemporary economic theory. It is highly abstract, but by carefully specifying the conditions under which market equilibrium obtains, it provides an analytical basis for understanding not only markets, but also market failures (cases where competitive markets cannot exist, or lead to socially inefficient outcomes). If one accepts this model, one then analyzes a real-world economy by assessing where the real economy deviates from the model, and what we might expect to occur in light of of this deviation. There is no assurance that this methodology will be successful (Google the Theory of the Second Best), but generally it is the best we have, and it appears to work well in practice.

At the time the architects of GE theory achieved their successes in the mid-twentieth century, which consisted of proving the existence of equilibrium under very general conditions, they fully expected that the theory would extend to proving stability and perhaps even uniqueness in the course of time. To illustrate just how far GE theory was from a plausible dynamic model, Walras had proposed that equilibrium would be achieved by having an "courtier" (broker) or "crieur" (crier) call out prices and adjust them according to the degree of excess demand or supply in each market, until equilibrium was achieved. The idea of what in English we call the "auctioneer" equilibrating a decentralized market economy is so bizarre and indeed absurd that leaving GE theory at this level would of course be highly embarrassing to economic theory. To add insult to injury, it was shown by Saari in 1985 and Bala and Majumdar in 1992, that even with an auctioneer, and with very generous auxiliary assumptions, general equilibrium prices would be unstable, and indeed chaotic. The fact is that to this day there is no plausible model of general equilibrium exhibiting dynamic stability.

It follows that there is absolutely no reason given by economic theory for anything like the "market fundamentalism" that Soros critiques. In particular, there is nothing in economic theory that suggests the impossibility, or even rarity, of crashes, bubbles, and meltdowns. Nothing, I stress, at all.

Nevertheless, I have noticed that despite the above undeniable truth, most economists are indeed market fundamentalists when it comes to issues of stability of equilibrium (they are not fundamentalists when it comes to market failure and the need to regulate the market economy, however). I still recall the moment I heard Alan Greenspan, former Federal Reserve Chairman tell Congress that "Those of us who have looked to the self-interest of lending institutions to protect shareholder's equity -- myself especially -- are in a state of shocked disbelief." I myself stood in shocked disbelief that a real economist, not some free-market crazy, could harbor such theoretically ill-founded beliefs. But, in fact, some of the most influential and perceptive economic theorists share this same believe. In their book Animal Spirits, for instance, Nobel prize winning economic George Akerlof and distinguished (and iconoclastic) Yale professor Robert Shiller, say that "if we thought that people were totally rational, and that they acted almost entirely out of economic motives, we too would believe that government should play little role in the regulation of financial markets, and perhaps even in determining the level of aggregate demand." (p. 173). This is a shockingly uninformed statement. There is nothing in economic theory that says that rational individuals interacting on markets will produce stable, efficient outcomes! The GE model, which is the general framework for investigating macroeconomic behavior on a theoretical level, says that if there are no market externalities, there are market-clearing equilibria that are Pareto-efficient. However, as has been long understood, this model has absolutely no attractive dynamical properties.

I conclude that Soros is correct, not in his critique of economic theory, but rather in his critique of market fundamentalism, the reigning ideology of mainstream economists. Where this ideology comes from, I do not know. I do not recall being taught it by my professors at Harvard, and I do not believe it is in the leading graduate microeconomic textbooks. This doctrine is indeed central to the "rational expectations" school of macroeconomics, and perhaps this is where the idea comes from. On the other hand, neither Greenspan nor Akerlof and Shiller belong to this school of thought, so the ideology is probably of more general proportions. For the record, Soros' critique of the rational expectations school in this book is quite cogent, and I am in complete agreement with him. Only an academic the Ivory Tower could place credence in so bizarre a theory.

Soros' own analysis of where economics went wrong is incorrect. Soros studied at the London School of Economics at a time when the old Marshallian tradition was prominent, and before the GE theory took hold. The Marshallian school analyzed single markets in terms of supply and demand, and assumed that the determinants of supply and demand were distinct, so the two schedules were independent. Soros attacks this notion by claiming interdependence of supply and demand, and he dead right. However, the GE model explicitly accepts this interdependence, without which it would be easy to supply analytically tractable dynamics and plausible stability conditions. However, the market economy is inextricably interconnected, and there is no possibility of treating demand and supply independently.

Soros thus incorrectly attributes "market fundamentalism" to economic theory, whereas in fact it is an aspect of the ideology of economists, not an implication of the GE theory that they learn and use. Because Soros has not studied modern economic theory, he attributes the ideology to an improper independence of supply and demand, which is a attributed of old-fashioned Marshallian theory, not modern GE theory.

Soros then goes on to propose an alternative that is geared to overcoming the independence of the two sides of the market. He does this by developing a philosophical system in which individuals interact with the world in both a "cognitive" and a "manipulative" manner, the first having the aim of understand, the second of influencing and changing. According to Soros' reasoning, the two functions can operate at cross-purposes. Most important, we can analyze the past using the cognitive function and intervene in the present using the manipulative function, which leads to a situation in which the future cannot be known. This two-way connection between facts and opinions Soros calls "reflectivity." Because of reflexivity, the economy involves fundamental uncertainty of form not recognized in standard economic theory. The impossibility of stability of equilibrium is due this reflexivity.

Soros' argument is too speculative for economists to take seriously. Economists work with models. Someone who does not like the GE model is obliged to find an alternative model that does a better job. Soros does not supply another model, so most economists will simply ignore him (given his business acumen, they will `respectfully' ignore him). However, I have worked in this area of the past six or seven years, and my research lends some serious support to his argument. Let me explain.

The GE model has no attractive dynamical properties, but the institutions it recognizes (markets, prices, consumers, producers, firms, money, capital goods, etc.) really exist and more or less operate the way the theory describes. The real world market economies show significant stochastic behavior (there are lots of more or less random fluctuations) but the fluctuations occur around an equilibrium condition that, while rarely attained, is more or less, on the average, approximated over the medium run, and which changes only in response to changes in underlying technology, resource availability, and consumer tastes. This indicated to me, as it does to Soros, is that the problem with the GE model is that it assumes individuals know too much, or rather, that they share too much knowledge. Rather, as stressed by the great economist Friedrich von Hayek, knowledge is distributed all over the economy, each individual economic actor only knowing a small part of the whole.

My reaction to this situation was to develop a computer model of the economy using what is called agent-based modeling. My model appears as "The Dynamics of General Equilibrium", Economic Journal 117 (2007):1289-1309. This model assumes (a) each individual knows only a small part of the total picture, and in particular, has his own, private estimate of prices, and (b) individuals improve their position as firms, workers, and entrepreneurs, by copying the behavior others who appear to be more successful than themselves, as well as experimenting and learning from variations in their own behavior. There are two main findings to be had from this exercise. The first is that the economy does tend toward equilibrium, and if shocked, tends to return to this medium-run equilibrium. Thus the economists' ideological faith in equilibrium seems vindicated.

However, the second finding is that there are significant excursions away from equilibrium, to the point that disequilibrium is the general conditions, as Soros says. Indeed, these excursions are frequent, and periodically sufficient to produce the sorts of bubbles and crises that we see around us. Moreover, these large excursions away from equilibrium occur without any aggregate macroeconomic shock, and are due to what I call "local resonances" that are characteristic of the sort of complex, dynamical, and nonlinear system that a general equilibrium system seems to be. For an introduction to the economy as a complex system, see Eric Beinhocker, The Origins of Wealth: Evolution, Complexity, and the Radical Remaking of Economics (Harvard Business School Press, 2006). Such local resonances are perhaps the codification of Soros' reflexive tenencies.

In short, I believe Soros is closer to understanding the current crisis than the free-market fundamentalists, the liberal super-regulators, or the behavioral economists who blame human irrationality. My formal model, using agent-based techniques, produces the sorts of outcomes Soros stresses, and it does so for reasons that are analytical refinements of Soros' "reflexivity." His pronouncements should be taken seriously, although considerable analytical refinement will be need to turn them into defensible policy tools.
Help other customers find the most helpful reviews 
Was this review helpful to you? Yes No

[Add comment]
Post a comment
To insert a product link use the format: [[ASIN:ASIN product-title]] (What's this?)
Amazon will display this name with all your submissions, including reviews and discussion posts. (Learn more)
Name:
Badge:
This badge will be assigned to you and will appear along with your name.
There was an error. Please try again.
Please see the full guidelines here.

Official Comment

As a representative of this product you can post one Official Comment on this review. It will appear immediately below the review wherever it is displayed.   Learn more
The following name and badge will be shown with this comment:
 (edit name)
After clicking the Post button you will be asked to create your public name, which will be shown with all your contributions.

Is this your product?

If you are the author, artist, manufacturer or an official representative of this product, you can post an Official Comment on this review. It will appear immediately below the review wherever it is displayed.  Learn more
Otherwise, you can still post a regular comment on this review.

Is this your product?

If you are the author, artist, manufacturer or an official representative of this product, you can post an Official Comment on this review. It will appear immediately below the review wherever it is displayed.   Learn more
 
System timed out

We were unable to verify whether you represent the product. Please try again later, or retry now. Otherwise you can post a regular comment.

Since you previously posted an Official Comment, this comment will appear in the comment section below. You also have the option to edit your Official Comment.   Learn more
The maximum number of Official Comments have been posted. This comment will appear in the comment section below.   Learn more
Prompts for sign-in
 

Comments

Tracked by 4 customers

Sort: Oldest first | Newest first
Showing 1-10 of 10 posts in this discussion
Initial post: Jun 6, 2009 9:07:27 AM PDT
B. Handshue says:
Brilliant review! Your explanations of the problems of general equilibrium are easy and readable to the layman.

Posted on Oct 17, 2009 8:10:57 PM PDT
[Deleted by the author on Oct 17, 2009 8:11:35 PM PDT]

Posted on Oct 17, 2009 8:13:51 PM PDT
Whoops. Sorry about the double post.

IMHCO those searching for the causes of economic depressions, like the one we are in now, under macroeconomic theories regarding price equilibrium are turning over the wrong rock. Or to switch metaphors, yes water always seeks its own level. Yes, the ocean is always roiling. So what does that tell you about the cause of a tsunami? Nothing.

Posted on Jan 5, 2010 2:21:29 PM PST
Last edited by the author on Jan 5, 2010 2:23:39 PM PST
Sam I Am says:
[Customers don't think this post adds to the discussion. Show post anyway. Show all unhelpful posts.]

In reply to an earlier post on Jan 5, 2010 4:30:21 PM PST
I think you misrepresent Soros. He is not a socialist. He is a social reformer. Nor is he an idealist, of course. He has funded very down-to-earth social projects, including a university where I teach-Central European University. I know he is not cynical; rather, he is quite impassioned about make social change happen. Nor is he greedy. He gives away lots of money.

Posted on Feb 5, 2010 8:50:05 AM PST
How much are you worth and do you have a better track record than George Soros.

Posted on Jul 10, 2010 12:05:33 PM PDT
vpenner2 says:
Thank you for an illuminating and well thought through review. It is interesting that you have explored Soros' ideas further with agent-based modelling.

Posted on Jun 27, 2012 2:07:03 AM PDT
You appreciate the formal criteria of "GE," by claiming it represents real-world institutions. This seems a minimal basis; Marx, Ricardo, Malthus, etc., prior to GE, factored real-world institutions in their models. The abstract legitimacy of equilibrium theory isn't proven by its performance, which rarely achieves much validity when confronted with big data. But you suggest it's useful as a truism, a normative guide, that researchers use by testing how far from equilibrium their data or model is. No wonder Soros, who studied under Popper, feels this is an abuse of scientific method: economists treat the falsification of their theory as a way to prove things. This would be like saying all medicine is a placebo, and studying medical outcomes as divergences from that norm. How interesting, anti-biotics seem much more effective than our placebo model suggests; must be due to a distortion in the infection.

It's the overt mathematization of GE that makes it so powerful, not as a scientific instrument, but as a mark of scientistic distinction. Ironic, then, that its Newtonian calculus basis is very 19th century; the real world is not smooth and differentiable. Economics has a lot of hubris, using deductive methods so often. Given our very real ignorance about macroeconomic dynamics, economic science should be inductive, data-driven. Using self-organization models to create pictures of pseudo-reality doesn't prove much, unless you can predict the future. The almost complete failure of so many economists to predict the Great Recession is a testament to their theoretical weakness.

In reply to an earlier post on Jun 29, 2012 6:53:39 AM PDT
Your critique is of Macroeconomic models, which sometimes call themselves GE models, but in fact are highly aggregated and predict very poorly, as you suggest.

The basic GE model that I work with is a Markov process model that has not been fully explored because it is very new (several groups of researchers are now working oin this).

All science is an interaction between deduction and induction. Induction in economics is very, very, important, as you say. However, it is not an abuse of scientific method to try to develop analytical models that represent real economic dynamics. that is what I try to do.

Modern macroeconomics has no room for financial dynamics, so of course it could not predict macroeconomic instability based on financial instability.

The point is not to predict the future. The future in complex systems cannot be predicted, and predictions in such systems affect the future! The point is to identify fragile aspects of the economy and render them more robust. Economists are now in the process of trying to do that by integrating financial sectors in to decentralized models of market competition.

In reply to an earlier post on Jun 29, 2012 3:34:30 PM PDT
Deductive knowledge, as an ideal, defines things. If X is true, then A. Inductive knowledge concerns things dependent on specific circumstances. If A is observed, then X is likely. These things may or may not generate hypothesis, but evidence makes them more probable. Science uses a middle way: evidence removes uncertainty like a filter. Evidence makes alternative explanations less probable, if A, then non-X less likely.

Deduction: Researchers propose a medicine to treat a disease based on prior facts.
Middle-way: If a medicine is tested, researchers assess probability of success given placebo effect. Placebo is an alternative the test must overcome.
Induction: If a medicine always works it's effective.

The middle-way is like abduction, except it negates counterfactuals. Abduction: the grass is wet, it must have rained last night. Counterfactual: if it was clear last night, the grass would be dry. Middle way: the grass is wet; it probably wasn't clear last night.

GE is often deductive: all economic relations generate equilibrium. Every affair that has economic relations will reach equilibrium.
Induction: all similar affairs reach equilibrium, so this affair is probably economic.
Middle-way: History does not reach equilibrium, but suppose economics does. If this affair reaches equilibrium, it is not historical.

Negating counterfactuals is a powerful tool. GE proposes that tax policy generates equilibrium. If taxes are in equilibrium, they are not historical. Tax policy is clearly historical. GE is false.

But GE claims "conditionality", such as "historically conditioned." Under specific historical regimes, different equilibrium result. If Allende, one equilibrium, if Pinochet, then another. GE might say historians observe the transition of one historically conditioned equilibrium to another. Few historians agree, because they consider change endogenous to history. Allende arose because of economic change; economic change enabled Pinochet's coup, then economic change led to his fall. Gross simplification, but equilibrium do not exist in economic history.

GE deduction is valid: if all economic activity can be modeled as differentiable linear functions, then equilibrium occur. But valid deductive logic is not necessarily truth. Sound deduction depends on the assumption. If much economic activity cannot be modeled as differentiable linear functions, equilibrium are not implied.

Perhaps equilibrium theory can become the placebo of future research design. Test a thesis: if it does no better than equilibrium analysis, it's false. Today the test goes: if equilibrium tests don't satisfy data, the data represent distorted conditions. Today's method is lazy, and probably politically oppressive.
‹ Previous 1 Next ›

Review Details

Item

Reviewer


Location: Northampton, MA USA

Top Reviewer Ranking: 2,805